Risk management in agribusiness Essay Example

Expected utility model and possible investment advice

Lecturer

TABLE OF CONTENTS

1.0 Introduction 3

2.0 Expected utility computation 3

3.0 Expected money value 5

4.0 Crop with greatest utility 6

5.0 Certainty equivalence 7

6.0 Risk premium for the crops 8

7.0 Choice of insurance with government subsidy 8

8.0 Disease insurance 9

9.0 Hedging table 10

REFERENCES 11

1.0 Introduction

Making the right choices during investments is very key. This is because risk is real and could quickly reduce a person’s investments without warning (Bolton, Chen, and Wang, 2013). However, Pattillo (2016) affirms thattaking risks is also part of investment since fear of risk is also fear of prosperity. Careful investors according to the advice of Rubaltelli, et al. (2015) can therefore only minimize risk levels or avoid obvious risks when they plan through an assessment of all possible alternatives and their scales of risk. This paper provides an expert advice on risk management and decisions for investment in an Agricultural setup.

2.0 Expected utility computation

In economics, expected utility is a term that summarizes the expected utility that an entity should probably reach under certain circumstances and is calculated by computing weighted averages of all probable outcomes under specific circumstances (Fishburn, 2013). The weights, Cerreia‐Vioglio, Dillenberger, and Ortoleva (2015) intimates, are assigned as likelihood to occur or the value of probability of a certain event occurring. Fishburn (2013) argues that the expected utility model teaches that the all possible utility levels’ weighted average, under a level of uncertainty, will be equal to utility at a given time.The utility of the farmer at different income levels is as follows:

Utility of farmer Sally Whitwell at different income levels

Expected income (AUD’ 000)

Sally Whitwell’s utility

0

From the table, the expected utility is computed with regression analysis as follows:

Regression Statistics

Multiple R

0.978778329

0.958007018

Adjusted R Square

0.952757895

Standard Error

65.80673409

The r-square value is 0.958 implying about 95.8% perfection in the model used. The standard error is quite high at 65.80 implying that the risk value for the expected utility is also high. However, the significance of this is estimated using ANOVA shown below.

Significance F

Regression

790355.79

790355.79

182.5080242

8.64955E-07

Residual

34644.21001

4330.526251

The ANOVA data shows a very significant relationship for the standard error with a high F-value of 182 significant at 99% confidence interval. Regression coefficients are shown below:

Coefficients

Standard Error

Lower 95%

Upper 95%

Intercept

-82.884607

44.597783

-1.85849

0.1001623

-185.7272

19.958066

Sally Whitwell’s utility

8.97112133

0.6640575

13.50955

8.6495E-7

7.439801

10.502440

The regression data shown above leads to a computation of the utility line plot shown below.

Risk management in agribusiness

The y intercept is presented by -82.885 i.e. expected income against the expected utility of 8.9711. this means that at estimated utility of 8.9711, Sally would get a loss of $82.885 implying a high risk. Sally therefore needs a utility value of at least 10.50 to earn an estimated $19.95. The advice is that Sally should consider heavy investment, more than $100 to have substantial utility.

At expected income of $600, risk aversion, absolute and relative is given as follows;

Absolute risk aversion (600) = 8.9711x — 82.885

682.885=8.9711(x)

x=76.1205426

Relative risk aversion = absolute risk±standard error

= $76.1205426±44.597783

=31-5223 or 120.7182

3.0 Expected money value

Expected money value is computed for each of the following crops

Investment options

  1. Carrot=20(200)+25(500)+30(700)+25(-200)

=4000+12500+21000-5000

  1. Corn =2000+7500+12000-7500

  1. Kale = 6000+10000+15000-2500

  1. Lettuce=-6000 – 2500+12000+12500

  1. Tomato=2000+7500+18000-2500

4.0 Crop with greatest utility

Expected utility is given by the function Risk management in agribusiness  1

Expected utility (x) is given by:

EU(x)=Risk management in agribusiness  2.

The carrot produceshighest money hence, since it is a directly proportional function, the highest utility is from the carrot crop: substituting EU(x)= Risk management in agribusiness  3 with the carrot expected income is given as= Risk management in agribusiness  4

=32582.885/8.9711

= 3631.98.

5.0 Certainty equivalence

The certainty equivalence was ascertained from the 95% confidence interval of each of the crops as shown with the descriptive statistics below.

Carrot 

Standard Error

195.789002

154.784796

131.497782

193.1105038

149.303940

Standard Deviation

391.578004

309.569593

262.995564

386.2210075

298.607881

Sample Variance

153333.333

95833.3333

69166.6666

149166.6667

89166.6666

Kurtosis

-0.7684310

0.757655955

2.23486718

-4.40922568

-0.4161062

Skewness

-0.5995806

-1.13762436

-1.4430588

-0.1692376

0.42252141

Confidence Level(95.0%)

623.087986

492.594304

418.484630

614.563809

475.15177

The certainty for each crop i.e. what ought to be invested to yield income at 95% confidence interval is as follows:

  1. Carrot = 623.0879863

  2. Corn = 492.5943048

  3. Kale = 418.4846304

  4. Lettuce = 614.5638092

  5. Tomato = 475.151774

Certainty level for carrot is best of all the crops while kale crop remains the most uncertain based on the computations shown above. Insurance is therefore recommended for the high risk crops i.e. kale, corn and tomato.

6.0 Risk premium for the crops

According to Damodaran (2016), risk premium is defined as the risk free rate less the return on an investment that is expected to be yielded. The form of compensation that investors can tolerate in case of extra risk, argues Peng and Wang(2016), is called an asset risk premium while a risk free asset is one that demonstrates no risk in case of an investment. The risk premium for each crop is given by the function Y= 8.9711x — 82.885 from the regression analysis where y is the sum of expected crop investment. Thus Risk management in agribusiness  5. The risk premium for the crops is therefore as follows:

Carrot Risk management in agribusiness  6= 143.002

Corn x = Risk management in agribusiness  7 = 64.97

Kale x = Risk management in agribusiness  8 = 131.86

Lettuce x = Risk management in agribusiness  9 = 64.97

Tomato x = Risk management in agribusiness  10 = 109.56

7.0 Choice of insurance with government subsidy

The risk premium less the $30 government subsidy for weather is given as follows:

Carrot = 113.002

Corn = 34.97

Kale = 101.86

Lettuce = 34.97

Tomato = 79.56

The data indicates that without the whether risk using government subsidy, the risk is still significant for kales, carrots and tomato. Insurance is therefore still advised for these three crops but can be foregone for corn and lettuce crops.

8.0 Disease insurance

Expected profit per crop is 70% while the probability of the disease risk is 30%. This has the implication that the expected profits for each crop is as follows (refer back to expected money value.

Carrot = 70% of $32500 = $22750

Corn = 70% x $14000 = $9800

Kale = 70% of $28500 = $19950

Lettuce = 70% of $16000 = $11200

Tomato = 70% of $25000 = $17500

Insurance value is therefore given by Disease risk of 30% of money value for crop multiplied by the cost per dollar. The computations per crop is as follows:

  1. Carrot = 30% of 22750*35 cents

=$2388.75

  1. Corn = 30% x $9800 x 35 cents

  1. Kale = 30% x $19950 x 35 cents

=$2094.75

  1. Lettuce = 30% x $11200 x 35 cents

  1. Tomato = 30% x $17500 x 35 cents

=$1837.5

9.0 Hedging table

In finance and insurance, hedging is a strategy that investors use to reduce the risk of a peril hence the price of asset movements risk (Moschini, and Hennessy, 2001). As Conlon, Cotter and Gençay (2016) posit, hedging could involve taking things such as security for example a futures contract. Other scholars refer to hedging as the same thing as an insurance policy hence hedging is confined to taking an insurance policy for the specific risks that are prone in a particular area of investment (Turcic, Kouvelis, and Bolandifar, 2014). In this case probable insurance policies would be crop disease policy and weather insurance policy. Hedging also is considerate of risk-reward tradeoffwhich is meant to reduce the risk potentially though it may also chip away probable gains. Hedging’s shouldn’t be though as free in the end because some gains are lost in an equal manner as potential risks. For example, when an insurance policy is meant to cover weather conditions such as floods, whereas the monthly bills goes up,in case there is no flood, the holder of the policy gets no payout. However, a perfect hedge helps an investor to eliminate a portfolio of risks in a position hence referred to as 100% inverse correlation in relation to the investment thought to be vulnerable (Conlon, Cotter and Gençay, 2016). The table below refers to the hedging for the case study preparing hedge with options (constant cash and future prices) where the basis is held constant.

Cash and futures

Options price

Today 1st Futures 1
Nov: Cash $5.10 per bushel (wheat)st Jan: $5.40 bushel

(pay $1,000 plus commission)
Purchase $5.50/bushel put at $0.20 bushel

Later 1st Futures 1
Dec: Sell wheat locally at $5.00 per bushelst Jan $5.10 per bushel

Option expires worthless
(receive $0)
Sell $5.40/bushel put at $0/bushel

Less option premium loss $0.20/bushel
Less commission $0.03/bushel
Cash price paid $5.00/bushelNet selling price $5.23/bushel

List of References

Bolton, P., Chen, H. and Wang, N., 2013. Market timing, investment, and risk management. Journal of Financial Economics109(1), pp.40-62.

Cerreia‐Vioglio, S., Dillenberger, D. and Ortoleva, P., 2015. Cautious expected utility and the certainty effect. Econometrica83(2), pp.693-728.

Conlon, T., Cotter, J. and Gençay, R., 2016. Commodity futures hedging, risk aversion and the hedging horizon. The European Journal of Finance22(15), pp.1534-1560.

Damodaran, A., 2016. Equity risk premiums (ERP): Determinants, estimation and implications–The 2016 Edition.

Fishburn, P.C., 2013. The foundations of expected utility (Vol. 31). Springer Science & Business Media.

Moschini, G. and Hennessy, D.A., 2001. Uncertainty, risk aversion, and risk management for agricultural producers. Handbook of agricultural economics1, pp.87-153.

Pattillo, C., 2016. 4 Risk, Financial Constraints and Equipment Investment. Investment and Risk in Africa, p.96.

Peng, X. and Wang, W., 2016. Optimal investment and risk control for an insurer under inside information. Insurance: Mathematics and Economics69, pp.104-116.

Rubaltelli, E., Agnoli, S., Rancan, M. and Pozzoli, T., 2015. Emotional Intelligence and risk taking in investment decision-making (No. 15107). Universita di Modena e Reggio Emilia, Dipartimento di Economia» Marco Biagi».

Turcic, D., Kouvelis, P. and Bolandifar, E., 2014. Risk-Aversion Happens: Hedging Commodity Material Purchases in a Bilateral Supply Chain.